adplus-dvertising
Connect with us

Politics

Carbon Tax Border Adjustments: Good Politics, Bad For Consumers? – Forbes

Published

 on


In June the European Union’s director general for trade announced that the EU is developing a carbon border levy that will be imposed on imports of carbon-intensive goods such as steel and cement.  The border adjustment, part of Europe’s Green Deal to dramatically curtail carbon dioxide emissions, in part through carbon pricing, will aim to protect the bloc’s industries from cheaper foreign goods from countries where no carbon price is in place.  The EU will release its finished proposal by mid-2021.

On this side of the Atlantic, the eight carbon pricing proposals now circulating through Congress all include border adjustments to protect American companies from imports not burdened by a carbon price in their country of origin.  A corresponding refund of the carbon price on American exports would help ensure that American goods sold overseas are not priced out of foreign markets.

With all of the attention paid to carbon border adjustments, it would seem that they must be a good thing.  Yet the full story is more complex.  Border adjustments are a zero-sum game, and where there are winners, there are likely those that won’t fare so well.

Border adjustments are meant to protect carbon-intensive domestic industries from foreign competitors not subject to a carbon price, and reduce the temptation for industries to transplant production overseas to avoid higher costs, preserving jobs at home.

Yet, while border adjustments alleviate economic pressure on polluting industries, at least in the near term, they transfer that pressure onto consumers.  In an oft-cited 2016 paper, University of Chicago law professor David Weisbach and Yale economist Sam Kortum explore the impact of border adjustments on consumers. 

“The basic question we wanted to ask is whether border adjustments would make the American people overall better off,” Weisbach recently said.  “Not just the industries that are complaining about the carbon tax, but really everybody.”

“We found out that they probably don’t help U.S. consumers.”

Border adjustments level the competitive playing field by levying a carbon fee on imports that’s equivalent to the carbon price borne by products made at home.  Similarly, exports from a country with a carbon tax, such as a hypothetical future U.S. with serious national climate policy, have their carbon price refunded at the border, eliminating any pricing handicap in export markets.

While the carbon price burden is lifted from domestic industry, the underlying cost of carbon still exists.  That cost is shifted onto domestic consumers, who now pay the baked-in price of a carbon tax for goods produced domestically, and on imports.  Meanwhile, foreign consumers are freed of any carbon price burden.

“What the border adjustment has done effectively is shift the tax off of foreign consumers and put it on U.S. consumers,” Weisbach says.  “Foreign consumers are really happy about this. And U.S. consumers — well, not so much.”

Border adjustments may also reduce the competitive pressure on industries to reduce the carbon intensity of their operations and products versus manufacturers of similar products, as carbon content becomes less relevant to pricing.  Of course, consumers will still have an incentive to seek out substitutes to carbon-intensive goods, to the extent they’re available.  But the pressure on companies to become more carbon efficient versus their direct competition is diluted.

And it might be argued that by preserving jobs in fossil energy production and carbon-intensive manufacturing, border adjustments do ultimately help consumers.

“To the extent that we think that border adjustments are really preventing those industries from shifting out of the U.S., it’s not really clear how much in the long-run you’re going to stop those industries from having to retool anyway,” says Weisbach.  “In some ways, it’s a rearguard action.”

“And it’s not clear that border adjustments, by trying to continue to protect these industries from retooling are really doing something that’s good for the U.S. in the long-run.”

“I think the supporters of border adjustments are the affected industries,” he says. “They are the loudest voices out there, and they have an easy time making their views known in Washington. But nobody is out there speaking the American public generally.”

Competitive issues aside, Weisbach and Kortum found that border adjustments will be immensely complex and costly to implement.  Imagine the difficulty in calculating the carbon content of a car produced overseas. That car will have components produced by a number of suppliers, through a variety of methods and from a potentially dizzying array of source countries.

“The global supply chain is just too complex,” says Weisbach.  “There’s no way to impose a reasonably accurate border adjustment, and that’s why they’d be limited to simple fuels or steel.  Implementing on any comprehensive basis would be impossible, the cost would be overwhelming.”

“So border adjustments are crude and inaccurate, and then you induce problems because you’re not getting the incentives you want.”

None of which is to say that carbon pricing itself isn’t a good idea.  “There could be huge benefits in having a carbon tax,” says economist Kortum.  “It’s really an issue of whether you should leave it on the extraction sector, the energy sector, or push it downstream either to the production sector or to the consumers.”

The easiest solution by far would be the global adoption of a uniform carbon price.  The Paris Climate Agreement takes a step in this direction by driving nearly all countries toward some level of carbon price, either explicit or implicit.

“I think the big picture is that if all countries get together and impose a common policy, that’s just by far the best way to solve the issue of climate change,” says Kortum.  “And what we’ve been talking about today is the second-best situations, where only some countries have a policy.”

Nobel laurate economist William Nordhaus has proposed an alternate solution he calls Climate Clubs, whereby a uniform tariff is imposed on all imports from countries that don’t have a carbon price.  The plan is theoretically made stronger because countries with carbon pricing would band together to levy the tariffs, putting extra pressure on non-conformers to join the community of carbon pricing nations.  Yet another option would be to implement border adjustments that are based on industry-average emissions for a given class of goods, avoiding the complexity that would come with measuring the carbon pollution for individual products.

Kortum suggests that a partial border adjustment that still leaves pressure on extracting industries may also be a good compromise.

All of these are being explored.  What’s clear is that border adjustments or their alternative are messy attempts to address the challenge of global warming, and the competitive implications of policies to address it, in a world that isn’t unified in its response to climate change.

Let’s block ads! (Why?)

728x90x4

Source link

Politics

NDP caving to Poilievre on carbon price, has no idea how to fight climate change: PM

Published

 on

 

OTTAWA – Prime Minister Justin Trudeau says the NDP is caving to political pressure from Conservative Leader Pierre Poilievre when it comes to their stance on the consumer carbon price.

Trudeau says he believes Jagmeet Singh and the NDP care about the environment, but it’s “increasingly obvious” that they have “no idea” what to do about climate change.

On Thursday, Singh said the NDP is working on a plan that wouldn’t put the burden of fighting climate change on the backs of workers, but wouldn’t say if that plan would include a consumer carbon price.

Singh’s noncommittal position comes as the NDP tries to frame itself as a credible alternative to the Conservatives in the next federal election.

Poilievre responded to that by releasing a video, pointing out that the NDP has voted time and again in favour of the Liberals’ carbon price.

British Columbia Premier David Eby also changed his tune on Thursday, promising that a re-elected NDP government would scrap the long-standing carbon tax and shift the burden to “big polluters,” if the federal government dropped its requirements.

This report by The Canadian Press was first published Sept. 13, 2024.

The Canadian Press. All rights reserved.

Source link

Continue Reading

Politics

Quebec consumer rights bill to regulate how merchants can ask for tips

Published

 on

 

Quebec wants to curb excessive tipping.

Simon Jolin-Barrette, minister responsible for consumer protection, has tabled a bill to force merchants to calculate tips based on the price before tax.

That means on a restaurant bill of $100, suggested tips would be calculated based on $100, not on $114.98 after provincial and federal sales taxes are added.

The bill would also increase the rebate offered to consumers when the price of an item at the cash register is higher than the shelf price, to $15 from $10.

And it would force grocery stores offering a discounted price for several items to clearly list the unit price as well.

Businesses would also have to indicate whether taxes will be added to the price of food products.

This report by The Canadian Press was first published Sept. 12, 2024.

The Canadian Press. All rights reserved.

Source link

Continue Reading

Politics

Youri Chassin quits CAQ to sit as Independent, second member to leave this month

Published

 on

 

Quebec legislature member Youri Chassin has announced he’s leaving the Coalition Avenir Québec government to sit as an Independent.

He announced the decision shortly after writing an open letter criticizing Premier François Legault’s government for abandoning its principles of smaller government.

In the letter published in Le Journal de Montréal and Le Journal de Québec, Chassin accused the party of falling back on what he called the old formula of throwing money at problems instead of looking to do things differently.

Chassin says public services are more fragile than ever, despite rising spending that pushed the province to a record $11-billion deficit projected in the last budget.

He is the second CAQ member to leave the party in a little more than one week, after economy and energy minister Pierre Fitzgibbon announced Sept. 4 he would leave because he lost motivation to do his job.

Chassin says he has no intention of joining another party and will instead sit as an Independent until the end of his term.

He has represented the Saint-Jérôme riding since the CAQ rose to power in 2018, but has not served in cabinet.

This report by The Canadian Press was first published Sept. 12, 2024.

The Canadian Press. All rights reserved.

Source link

Continue Reading

Trending